Subject: Unpaid graduate internships
In answer to Karen Elise Thomas's posting in Conservation DistList Instance: 17:49 Friday, January 9, 2004: Since graduating in 1983, I have followed the professionalizing of the profession and training programs, and the proliferation of training programs with a strong feeling that, despite regional developments, this is not a growth industry and probably never would be unless the creation of new museums becomes a growth industry. This is because, financially speaking, conservation is a luxury. If a government with limited funds has to choose between sustainable funding for public health or the conservation of cultural heritage, which would win? The same is for the private sector; which would you choose, a dental treatment or a conservation treatment? If a country experiences strong economic growth, there is more government money for conservation. Come the inevitable recession and conservation funding is cut, private people do not have their objects conserved, the antique trade suffers and so it goes on. This has certainly been my experience here in the Netherlands. I have a strong feeling that, internationally speaking, the funding of the conservation of moveable objects on a governmental or institutional level has had its peak. Or, more optimistically expressed, has had a peak in the late 1980's - early 1990's and we are now on the down side which could, of course, always change to up. About the supply and demand of graduates: In my experience, many people are attracted to conservation out of idealism (save the world by beginning with inanimate objects) or for an unconscious emotional motive (eg make objects whole = make themselves whole etc). Add to this romantic images of working on important/beautiful pieces in important collections and it is no surprise that many student applicants do not wish to register warnings of limited job and intern opportunities. The fact that most other graduate programs (Art History being a very strong example!) produce more graduates than the market can absorb, and this is accepted as normal, only reinforces my opinion on this matter. About reducing training programs: The training of conservators is very expensive, so the more students there are, the more economically efficient it is. Therefore most university programs have to run on the basis of a minimum number of students in order to ensure adequate funding for paying the lecturers. If the numbers of applicants fall below the minimum over some years, then the course is usually stopped. Which brings me to the issue of the continuity of knowledge. If the only training institution in a country stops teaching conservation or a conservation discipline, the accumulated structured knowledge and focus on that field fades away. This loss goes beyond the conservation of material, it can also apply to the technical knowledge of specific types of national cultural heritage: how things are made, which materials are used. A definite generation gap is also created as we are experiencing here with textile conservation. Since 1992 there have only been three graduates, from which only one has (part-time) employment. There are fewer and fewer textile conservators to keep the national textile conservation work group going--there is no new blood coming though to relieve the old timers who have been doing the committee work for many years. Due to lack of work quite a few, including myself, have stopped over the last few years. There are plenty of textiles in collections but no jobs and few contracts. There are no private collectors to speak of. The government funds conservation training but can not order museums to employ conservators, such as their own graduates who were dearly paid for by tax payers' money. To summarise 1. Conservation training is expensive so there must be large numbers of students to be economically viable. Institutions holding cultural heritage collections cannot be forced to employ conservators, even if both are funded by the same government department. It is easier to weed out weak students. The risk of over supply is that it leads to disappointed graduates and the evolutionary survival of the fittest. That is sad for a lot of graduates but that's the way it is. 2. If there are small numbers of students, the cost of training is out of proportion with production. The training institution becomes much more vulnerable to government funding cuts in times of recession. Risk of less weeding out of weak students. Risk of under supply of graduates--less talented graduates also get jobs. 3. Cutting training programs leads to loss of continuity and accumulated knowledge. Risk of continuing deterioration and loss of cultural heritage. This scenario has far greater consequences than having a pool of unemployed graduates. 4. Is the loss of cultural heritage always so bad? The preservation of national material cultural heritage and its accumulated knowledge is not just the responsibility of ministers of culture and museum directors. If the majority of the voting public is unconcerned, there will never be enough funding for truly sustainable conservation of cultural heritage. If a country or city loses cultural heritage through financial neglect through lack of public support, then that is a true reflection of that culture. Applying conservation funding in that case would lead to an untrue expression of how a country or city valued its material culture. A good recent example of expressed material cultural values is the case of our Western protests against the Taliban destroying buddhist statues in Afghanistan, their own land. The well meant protests, which clearly expressed Western culture, probably only served to encourage the perpetrators. The heavily damaged statues now express the culture of the then reigning Taliban. It is not a pretty sight but it is a powerful and true expression of material cultural. My conclusion is that over supply of graduates is better for the conservation community as a whole because it should lead to the better graduates getting sustainable employment in the long run. Jennifer Barnett (former textile conservator) Historical textiles research and consultation Oude Looiersstraat 65-67 1016 VH Amsterdam Netherlands +31 0 20 427 18 27 (phone/fax) *** Conservation DistList Instance 17:50 Distributed: Tuesday, January 20, 2004 Message Id: cdl-17-50-001 ***Received on Tuesday, 13 January, 2004